REGIONAL CLEAVAGES AND POLITICAL PARTICIPATION IN BRAZIL

CHAPTER 6
POLITICAL OPENNESS IN PERSPECTIVE



1. Political development and expanded participation

From 1945 to 1964, Brazil experienced a period of multi-party competition with progressively expanded popular participation - a period of "political development," as the optimistic theories of the early sixties call it. Almost ten years after that system collapsed, the country's political leadership still debates whether some kind of open system can be re-established or whether political liberalism is just an antique, which should be buried once and for all.(1)

Aside from the frustrated electoral experiences of 1930 and 1934, the 1945-64 period was the only time in Brazilian history during which political participation was really experienced and tried out. From a long-term historical perspective, it is possible to consider this period anomalous, because of the wave of democratization which swept Latin America after the Second World War, and which lasted between, fifteen and twenty years. True as this may be, it left the country with a taste of political freedom and openness which cannot and should not be easily erased. Conceptually, it brought another important variable to the analysis of the country's political system, that is, political participation.

This last chapter reflects on this experience, in an attempt to see whether the historical framework developed so far can be used for a proper conceptualization of the structure of the political participation system during this period, and whether a proper understanding of the political process during the period of political openness can furnish some cues for an under- standing of what happened afterwards and what might happen in the future. This combination of normative concern, conceptual synthesis and subjective evaluation certainly contributes to make this chapter the most speculative of all.

Representative politics is usually not very satisfying, and it is especially frustrating in a country which is as unequal and underdeveloped as Brazil. Its absence, however, can be worse, and many argue that this is at least the best possible arrangement to guarantee the values of individual rights and freedom of ideas. However, when the performance of this function is accompanied by inequalities, exploitation, waste and irrationality, values of administrative efficiency and redistribution of wealth tend to become dominant. Efficient as some non representative systems may become, the normative goals of individual rights and freedom of thought cannot be dismissed as simple manifestations of individualism or idle liberalism. It is true that formal political rights can mask actual social and economic inequalities and the suppression of rights. It is also true, as American experience shows, that political liberalism can lead to inefficiency, injustice, international bigotry and cold war(2); what is less certain, however, is that an anti- liberal system can do better.

In the case of Brazil, the quest for political openness is made particularly difficult by the failure. of its twenty-year experiment with representative democracy. The previous discussion concerning the continuous centralization of the country's political life in terms of "patrimonialism" hides the fact that there is a visible process of rationalization and increasing efficiency of the governmental apparatus. This rationalization tends to reduce the value attributed to formal procedures and guarantees of personal and political freedom in a democracy which is too obviously unfair and corrupt. If the price of this increase in efficiency and rationality is the loss of individual rights, freedom of organization, freedom of the press and habeas corpus only the few who personally suffer these restrictions will tend to oppose them; and among these, only some would be opposed by conviction. Either way, the case in favor of political openness and what it implies remains unfortunately too weak.

The other difficulty with political openness in Brazil is the lack of a simple, clear alternative political model. The traditional three-power, multi-party system has been demoralized. The remnants of the old political system, which subsists today in ARENA - MDB confrontations in the small rural areas of the country, do not furnish a basis for the further expansion of the political arena; on the contrary, they provide for their opponents a showcase of petty confrontations, small scale corruption, candidate incompetence and general lack of vote interest. A simple, direct, no-nonsense and efficient administration with strong military backing has much more appeal and is much more easy to understand. In order that an alternative model be socially and politically viable, it needs to be easily understood in the first place; only afterwards does it need to be operationally workable and politically possible.

For these and other reasons, the empirical prediction is that a viable system of open participation is not to be expected in Brazil in the near future. This does not mean, of course, that the problem does not remain, since empirical difficulties do not eliminate normative concerns. But good social science is always a combination of empirical awareness and workable solutions, and there is not much point in trying to pursue a political ideal which lacks a minimum of historical viability. And this viability depends, ultimately, on the process which would change a traditional patrimonialist structure into a highly rational and efficient administration. It is possible to think, for instance, that rationality implies freedom of thought and intellectual experimentation; some objective criteria of competence; areas of communication, and exchange of ideas. From this minimum, it is possible to expand to the inclusion of alternative values and perspectives, and alternative interests; and so on. It is possible, in short, to speculate on the functional necessity of including, in an expanding and well operated governmental apparatus, the elements of political openness. This openness will necessarily be very different from the traditional representative, multi-party system; but it may also be more effective in terms of the progressive incorporation of social groups into the society's system of decisions and allocation of values. We can try to redefine the expression "political development" in terms of this continuous expansion of the system of decisions and allocation of values, and discuss its perspectives in broad terms.

The lack of a proper treatment of problems of political development in an era of generalized political crisis is a peculiar feature of social science literature in the underdeveloped world, or at least in Latin America. This fact can be traced, intellectually speaking, to a more general tendency towards considering politics as fully implied in its economic and sociological context, having no existence of its own. It is curious how two contradictory tendencies led to this same outcome. The first tendency is pointed out by Prof. Samuel P. Huntington and comes from the North American lack of experience with political instability. It leads to the notion that a stable and successful political system is a natural consequence of economic development and an increase in social welfare.(3) The other tendency is Marxist in its origin: it tends to see the political sphere as a simple and direct consequence of the underlying structures of production.

Politics is thus seen in both cases as having no independent dynamics and determination. It is seen, from the left, as an instrument of the class struggles and the consolidation of the victorious social revolution and, from the right, as a simple technical operation of power management and control. A conceptual gap is therefore created between the specialists in economics and sociology, for whom the political process is a simple result of economic and social facts, and the specialists in government and public administration, for whom the political process is purely a technical problem, unrelated to what happens in the rest of the society. It is obvious that things are never as simple as that, but a host of empirical studies concerning the "political" (meaning social and economic) influences upon the governmental processes, or the "political" (meaning governmental) influences upon social and economic life are not enough to avoid the paradoxes of "depoliticized" political sociology and theories of government. This problem is particularly acute when what is at stake is the political process of a country such as Brazil, subjected to several social and economic development problems.

2. Political development: institutionalization and conflicts

Prof. Huntington's conceptualization of political development in terms of institutionalization is an attempt to define a dimension of social change, which is specifically political. He defines institutionalization as the "process through which organizations and processes acquire value and stability"; levels of institutionalization are said to be functions of levels of adaptability, complexity, autonomy, and coherence of the institutions.(4) Accordingly, a developed political system is the one which is able to adapt itself to new situations, develop new functions, incorporate new groups, play a plurality of functions and keep, at the same time, a basic level of consensus among the political community. It is a stable but not static system, and it possesses a legitimacy which transcends the circumstantial conveniences of the citizenry and plunges its roots into a historical past of stability, flexibility and legitimacy.

One of the determinants of political instability in underdeveloped contexts is, thus, this very instability: the series of breaks in the continuity of political institutions in these countries does not allow for the crystallization of those qualities of flexibility, adaptation, complexity, autonomy and coherence, which only time can accomplish. This conception leads, necessarily, to a conservative perspective, in its most precise meaning, namely, the perspective that there are values to preserve in old structures, and relatively high costs in the substitution of one structure by a new one.

But time is not the only independent variable, since institutional decay is also a possibility. A context of rapid changes, translated into continuous challenges for the political regime, can lead to the hardening and simplification of the political structure, which very often interrupts a previous process of maturation and institutionalization. The total lack of tensions also seems to lead to institutional stagnation, which can end up in sclerosis, rigidity and decay. Only a "reasonable" level of conflicts leads to institutional development in the sense above.(5) This "optimal level" of conflicts seems to be far from the rule in underdeveloped countries, and the known outcome is the more or less rapid deterioration of political institutions which, in one way or another, have worked up to the mid sixties. This is true in Latin America for the constitutional governments which replaced, for a short period, the populist regimes, and also seems to hold for the African governments established after the independence which, in most cases, have been replaced by military regimes. The general situation in the underdeveloped world is thus one of the institutional decay, even though this situation may be a necessary step towards placing power relations in a situation, which may or may not allow for the continuation of the development process at a higher level. This consideration obviously weakens the theory of gradual institutionalization as a prediction or prescription for political development in underdeveloped countries, but it does not reduce the relevance of the concept as an essential political variable. If we make the theoretical assumption that there is a long-term process of political development, which is somehow related with the also long-term processes of social and economic development, it is obvious that the conceptualization of political development should include other political variables besides institutionalization.

3. Political openness and institutionalization

A political system which is more institutionalized is, in principle, more able to integrate and legitimize new demands for participation than more rigid and immature systems. This legitimization and absorption of demands is what one might call "openness," and one can re-phrase the above by saying that, the more institutionalized a political system is, the more open it is. This is nearly a truism, if we consider "institutionalization" only in terms of adaptability, but it is a substantive proposition if we bring together the other dimensions of the concept. Empirical evidence is abundant: it ranges from the absorption of the working class parties in Western Europe to the troubles of performing the same kind of absorption by the less institutionalized regimes of Argentina. We should not, however, mistake "openness" for "democratization."

It was Schattschneider who said that "government by the people" is a pre democratic concept, in the sense that its formulation is previous to the existence of contemporary democratic regimes.(6) The definition of democracy offered by Schattschneider includes competition between leaders and organization, on one hand, and the presentation of political alternatives for the general public, who thus participate in the decision process, on the other. A political system which is able to absorb and process private demands, without allowing them to become political, can reach high levels of institutionalization without being democratic. Democracy, in Schattschneider's definition, begins to appear when the openness becomes political, and political demands of participation are accepted and legitimated as such. Participation is political when ii: transcends the level of specific group issues in two ways. First, the specific issues become general, and second, specific groups feel they have the right to influence and decide on questions previously considered private. A "participationist" political system of the fascist kind is anti-democratic, not because it seeks the substitution of territorial by functional representation, but because it does not allow functional groups to be concerned with questions of general interest. Territorial representation tends, in its origins, also to be private, given its dependence on stratification systems based on land tenure. If time has made it the highest expression of political representativeness, it is because of the growing multi-functionality of the territorial groups.

Two questions follow from the above. The first refers to the desirability of the two possible types of institutionalization, the democratic and participationist, or corporatist - fascist. It is quite likely that something like "participationist" is what Marx projected for the future society in which "politics" would cease to exist. The non-existence of politics means the non-existence of general problems, and a purely "technical" approach to specific problems of specific groups and sectors in society. Before the disappearance of general problems becomes real, however,(7) the forced suppression of political manifestations can lead to solutions of a technocratic type, in which technical capacity veils the fact that the area of bargaining and negotiations is not allowed to grow beyond the sphere of transactions between the groups concerned and the governmental sector responsible for its handling.

Once this is done, through coercion, ideological mobilization, or some combination of the two, a plurality of problems can arise. One is the possibility of corrupt practices, due to the low visibility of technical decisions combined with the technical unreliability of the decision makers.(8) Another is the pseudo technification of typically political areas, such as the assimilation of political with criminal acts, which are thus handled by a technical body - the police - and explained and interpreted by specialists of criminology and social control ("The social problem is a police problem," used to say a Brazilian President of the twenties.) A third problem is the "politicization" of essentially technical areas, in which the control of technical quality becomes less dependent on the internal consensus of an institutionalized scientific community and more dependent upon the political approval of the political regime. In general, the differences between the technical and the political become blurred or subject to short-term fluctuations. The advantages of this type of institutionalization can be many. It can be predominantly functional, including in some cases the establishment of a long-range policy of high investments and deferred gratification (as in the U.S.S.R.), in others, a long-range policy of social repression and apartheid (as in the white Republics in Africa), or even a combination of both, if the costs above are kept within tolerable bounds. The option between these two forms depends, on the political tradition of the country on one hand, and on the level and type of demands for participation, on the other.

When demands for participation tend to be high and politically oriented, as in Argentina, the institutionalization of a corporatist system does not seem to be possible. The alternative rests between the creation of a system of democratic participation and the continuation of a political system based on high levels of repression and political rigidity.(9)

Thus, we have the second question, referred to above, namely, the likelihood and stability of the different types of political participation. Part of the answer has already been given, namely, that the alternatives depend on the process of socioeconomic development and on the demands for participation, in the form of social mobilization, which follow from it. The second part of the answer is that the reaction of a given political system to a given level and type of demands is a function of its characteristics as a system, one of which is its level of institutionalization.

4. Socioeconomic development and political development

What this discussion has suggested is that the relation between what happens at the socioeconomic level and what happens at the political level is far from direct, starting with the fact that there are at least two important mediations between these two levels. We can speak of four analytical levels of change which deserve independent scrutiny: the levels of economic development, of change in the social structure, of the growth of political participation demands, and finally of political development. The autonomy of each of these processes does not mean that they are not empirically related, but simply that none of them can be completely understood through the others.(10)

Economic development here refers to the quantitative in- crease of per capita income or some equivalent indicator, in terms of technological change and the sectoral division of labor. The concept of social development often appears in the literature under the name of "modernization," and refers to an increase in the well-being of the populations, according to the standards of the modern mass consumption societies: consumption of industrialized goods, education, increase in life expectancy, newspaper consumption, means of communication, etc. Social development is more than a simple change in behavior and consumption patterns, since it brings with it an increase in the scope and intensity of communications, a progressive extension of the scale of social participation from the local to the national levels, and a change in the values and nature of the stratification system.(11) This general process of social development is sometimes called "mobilization," and has a direct bearing on political life in terms of an increase in participation.

But just as modernization is not a direct outcome of economic development, so political participation is not a direct effect of social modernization and mobilization. The modernization process very often precedes the process of economic growth, not only because of the host of phenomena designated in the expression "demonstration effect," but also because of the deliberate action of political centers in creating administrative and political nuclei, which work as poles of urbanization and modernization, combined very often with the disintegration of the more traditional rural economies. These urban centers generate, afterwards:, an industrial system which depends on them for its growth.

How is the process of social mobilization translated into demands for participation in public life? It is obvious that there is no simple answer to this question, which depends on two types of variables. The first type refers to the nature of the process of modernization and social mobilization. Lerner formulated very simple propositions, which suggested that political participation (measured by election turn-outs) would increase linearly with the process of urbanization and literacy; more recent analysis looks for the roots of variations in participation in the different types of synchronism and disequilibria found within the process of social and economic development. This topic is one of the most frequent in social development literature and it is enough to say here that a situation, in which economic development anticipates and leads the modernization process, creates a political climate which is radically different from those situations in which the process of modernization precedes and is not followed, except at a distance, by economic growth.(12) In the first case, political participation would probably tend to be more related to specific demands, leading to a progressive widening of the areas of group autonomy and political participation, whereas in the second, the conditions would be much more favorable to the emergence of symbolic forms of participation.

The second type of variable refers to factors which are more directly related to the political system, including its level of institutionalization. The responses of a political system to demands for participation only partially depend on the process of economic and social change, which its society undergoes. The transfer of the Portuguese royal family to Brazil in 1808 gave to this country a degree of institutionalization, which was unique in the Latin American context, and which explains much of the country's territorial integrity and political stability throughout the nineteenth century.

The proposition I would like to stress here is that the assumption of a causal chain going from the process of economic development to the structure and changes in the political system is untenable as a general proposition. Attempts to explain variations in the political structure as functions of socioeconomic change tend to consider the political sphere either as a mere outcome ("the political system is an instrument of the bourgeoisie") or as an obstacle ("the traditional power elites do not respond to the rising demands of the population...") to these processes. The final outcome is an extremely simplified perception of political factors. Sometimes, the alternative would be to take the political system as a starting point, but the difficulties here are related to the impossibility of making long-term processes of change follow from the general characteristics of the political system. It seems that the simultaneous use of both approaches is necessary, and that there is much to be gained if the changes in the economy and in the levels of social and political participation are considered as a process and combined with the analysis of politics as a system.

5. Political participation

It would be useful to organize these ideas in terms of S. Rokkan and S. M. Lipset's attempt to use Parsons' functional categories in an analysis of European politics.(13) Talcott Parsons, as it is well known, proposes an analytical division of the social systems in four general functions, which make the A-G-I-L framework (adaptation, goal achievement, integration, and pattern maintenance or latency). Also a Parsonian generalization is the proposition that when social systems tend to increase in size and complexity, the four analytical functions tend to become four empirically differentiated subsystems: the economic (for adaptive functions), the political (for the attainment of social goals), the subsystem of social and political participation (for the integrative functions) and the educational and family subsystem (for pattern maintenance functions) . Lipset and Rokkan are concerned, in their study, with the internal structure of the social and political participation subsystem, in terms of its internal cleavages. They show how this analysis leads to the study of two main axes of political cleavages: one connecting the adaptation and integration poles (the cross-local, functional cleavage) and the other connecting the goal achievement and latency poles (the center - periphery axis).

Another analytical road, which is being suggested here, is to think of the four subsystems as the loci of our processes of social change; the main task in the analysis of political participation systems will then be to evaluate how much of what happens in the subsystem of political participation is a function of the interactions among the other three.

Changes in A can be considered changes in the process of economic development; changes in G, a process of transformation and growth of the state structure; changes in L, transformations in society's values and motivations (which are usually measured in terms of changes in rates of urbanization and education, and are analyzed as a process of "modernization"); and finally, changes in I are essentially those related to transformations in the structure of social and political participation.

This essentially means that the structure of political participation is seen as an intervening variable between the State and the processes of economic development and modernization; this gives us four types of participation, depending on the dominant process:

TABLE 15
TYPES OF POLITICAL PARTICIPATION
Dominant Process (A, G, L) Dependent Process (A, G, L) Intervening Political Structure (I)
I. Economic Growth (A) Growth and Differentiation of the State (G) Political Representation: Party systems of the European kind
II. Growth and Differentiation of the State (G) Economic Growth (A) Political Co-optation: governmental political parties and one-party systems.
III. Modernization and Secularization of values (L) Growth and Differentiation of the State (G) Collective movements through autonomous mobilization: charismatic populism
IV. Growth and Differentiation of the State (G) Modernization and Secularization of values (L) Collective movements through induced mobilization: nationalism and paternalistic populism

When, in 1945, the political party system was reinstated, it unavoidably reflected the picture portrayed so far. What was peculiar in Brazil was that types I and II of political participation existed simultaneously in different geographical areas, and the new party system responded to both the geographical and the more structural elements.(14)

It seems proper to characterize the two political parties created by Vargas in terms of Co-optation The first of these parties was called the "Social Democratic Party" (PSD) . It was formed by the state and local leaders, who had been on good terms with the dictatorship. The term "coronelismo" is used in Brazilian political literature to characterize a type of rural boss, who derives his local strength from his access to patronage at the governmental level, and his ability to supply local votes for his party.(15) The coronel cannot survive without access to the government, and it is therefore not surprising that the party, which put these leaders together, became the biggest party in the country. A similar structure of co-optation was developed in the urban areas, through the Labor Party (PTB), to which Vargas affiliated himself. Its instruments of political control were the Ministry of Labor and the trade unions, politically and financially dependent on the Labor Ministry(16)

In both political parties, electoral power was derived from access to governmental positions and decision centers. Ideological issues were obviously secondary, and the major interests conveyed by political leaders were those referring to more positions, facilities and sinecures from the government. It would be, of course, too simplistic to say that these were the only goals and purposes of the parties. At the policy making level, more or less well defined goals of economic development, administrative efficiency and welfare were present. But these goals had few, if not contradictory, relations with the structures created to co-opt and handle their electoral support. What these two levels of the political system did have in common was the fact that both used to operate in almost purely distributive terms(17).

The opposition to this system came from different sources. There was a liberal opposition to Vargas, which combined urban middle classes with members of the local rural leadership, who had lost their access to the centers of decision making in the coronelismo system.(18) There were members of the army, who were impatient and intolerant with the price the government was paying for its maintenance in terms of political patronage. There were members of the working class who sought more militancy, greater ideological involvement of the trade unions, and more pro labor policies from the central government. There were military, intellectual and working-class groups which sought to orient the country's policy towards a more nationalist foreign policy.

It is possible to summarize all this in terms of how the access to government was obtained or sought. The co-optation system was either considered adequate, or in need of expansion, or in need of restrictions. What all the groups had in common, roughly speaking, was that their political influence was derived either from the control of governmental agencies, from their access to the government for a politics of patronage, or from their demands for more access for given groups and sectors. It may be disturbing to put mobilization and co-optation together, since mobilization is usually understood as a process of growing participation, political concern, and, hence, representation of interests. But it is certainly important to distinguish a process of "radicalization from above" from a process of growing demands for participation. One can assume that no "mobilization from above" will occur without some attempts at participation, and, in this sense, there is no co-optation without representation, that is, when there is nothing to be cooped; but what matters most, in terms of the system of political participation, is the relative weight of the demands for representation and the ability and resources to co-opt. Brazilian political figures like João Goulart and Brizola, who used their access to governmental positions and resources to create a radical political movement in 1963-64, are good examples of this combination. The ultimate example of this mixture of mobilization, control from above and the lack of actual structures of participation and representation is Fascism. When an economic system is dynamic, organized and structured social groups get together politically to influence political decisions that have some bearing on their share of society's goods, which are not owned patrimonialistically by the government or its bureaucracy. This kind of politics is what I am calling the "politics of representation," of which the liberal regimes of the Western World are the better known examples, although not the only conceivable arrangements.(19) Its essential condition is economic and/or organizational autonomy and self reference; in Brazil, this was developed mostly in the São Paulo area. Representation politics often took the form of liberal ideologies, which defined governmental intervention in politics, economics and welfare as an absolute evil; or of trade union movements, which had wage issues as a central concern, and which were based more on autonomous organization than on access to the Ministry of Labor(20). Finally, it developed as populist movements, which included elements of personal charisma corresponding to less structure and autonomy at the grass roots, but also to less direct control and patronage in the central government.(21)

The crucial test for the conversion of a set of relatively well articulated interest groups into a system of interest group politics lies in the measure in which there is a need for a generalization of private demands into broad and multi-purpose political movements. As Schattschneider suggests, this change from private to generalized demands arises when the bargaining process demands and allows for the incorporation of progressively wider sectors of society in the disputes. This perspective can be important if one asks why the São Paulo area did not provide the country with the strong representational political bodies, which its development and relative marginalization suggest. One kind of answer is that economic interests in the area were able to satisfy their demands in very specific terms, leading thus to actual depoliticization. The other answer is that much of São Paulo's economy was and still is strongly and directly open to the external market, and that this kind of linkage tends to make the issues of internal politics less salient. In either case, the net result was a combination of some interest politics, political apathy and relative marginality. Only when the stability of this arrangement was shaken did the level of political concern arise. It tended to manifest itself in terms of law and order, but, mostly, in terms of a liberal perspective, which abhorred politics and government interference in society. And this, of course, is a combination of goals, which is very difficult to hold together.

Figure 3 gives a simplified general picture of the Brazilian party system in the Third Republic.

FIGURE 3 POLITICAL PARTIES IN BRAZIL: CO-OPTATION AND MOBILIZATION

A good test case of this four-fold classification would be the analysis of the Brazilian labor movement in the 1945-64 period. As usual, the pattern of organization and political behavior of the trade union movement in São Paulo was remarkably different from the rest of the country. In the late forties and early fifties, some of the most militant and radical sectors of the Brazilian labor movement were based in São Paulo this was a period when the Brazilian Communist Party was stronger in São Paulo and in open confrontation with Vargas and with the control the Labor Party exerted upon the trade union organization in most of the country. Later, as the Labor, Communist and Nationalist movements tended to get together within the Labor Party, an array of independent, non-aligned unions started to emerge in São Paulo against the nationally dominant groups. A split occurred in the Third National Unions Conference held in São Paulo in 1960 on the attempt to create a nationally integrated Central Union, and the result was that the bulk of the Brazilian working class remained basically marginal to the national labor movement during the crucial years of 1960-63. One consequence of this was the astonishing disappearance of all traces of a national labor movement in Brazil after 1964(22). Thus, there are cases to fill in all four cells in the table combining co-optation vs. representation with radicalism, in the analysis of Brazil's labor movement; and this perspective helps to understand the movement's weakness and demise.

6. The changing voting patterns

A first picture of voting patterns in the 1945-64 period is given in Table 17. The alliance between the two parties created by Vargas, the Partido Social Democrático (PSD) and the Partido Trabalhista Brasileiro (Brazilian Labor Party, PTB) won all the elections except the one in 1960. Only in 1950 was there a split in the alliance, because of a personal move by Vargas, who had imposed his name for nomination but had not been accepted by the political leadership of the PSD (the figures in parentheses for 1950 correspond to the votes given to Cristiano Machado, the PSD candidate). Vargas's victory in 1950 is an indication not only of his personal charisma, but also of his direct command of the political. clientele, over and above the leadership of his major party. His major source of support was, however, urban and popular. The split within the PSD in Minas Gerais gave 32 percent of the votes to Cristiano Machado: this reflects the predominantly rural society and political structure of this state. It was quite clear that the PSD allegiance to Vargas was due less to ideological preferences than to the need to remain close to the source of power. When Vargas tried to transfer his personal leadership to his would-be political heir, João Goulart, the coalition became too threatening to be accepted by the most conservative sectors of the Social Democratic Party, which joined the opposition against the increasingly urban, working-class oriented and radical Labor Party.

TABLE 18
CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS. PARTY VOTES: THREE STATES, 1945-1962: PERCENTAGES OF VALID VOTES
  PSD PTB UDN PS? Others Coalitions and alliances
Guanabara (city of Rio de Janeiro)
1945 17.50% 26.90% 23.10% 2.30% 30.20%  
1950 14.00% 39.80% 17.90% 7.20% 21.10% . .
1954 10.30% 29.50% (32.90)% 11.10% 16.20% 35.00%
1958 14.80% 28.70% 33.80% 20.60% 2.10% 14.80%
1962 13.90% 49.80% 30.00% . 6.30% 63.70%
Minas Gerais
1945 47.00% 7.20% 22.20% . . 23.60%  
1950 38.70% 12.90% 29.30% 3.10% 16.00%  
1954 44.90% 12.50% 25.10% 4.50% 13.00%  
1958 43.00% 12.30% 19.90% 3.60% 12.20%  
1962 42.60% (15.40)% 31.30%   10.70% 15.40%
São Paulo
1945 36.00% 17.90% 21.50% 5.50% 19.10%  
1950 15.30% 20.90% 13.10% 29.20% 21.50%  
1954 29.40% 17.20% 8.70% 24.50% 20.20%  
1958   10.70% 9.70% (38.50)% 41.10% 62.00%
1962   (15.10)%   (28.20)% 56.70% 89.30%
Source: Calculated from Brasil, Tribunal Superior Eleitoral, Dados Estatísticos, vol. 6, 1.964. Figures in parentheses correspond to votes given to alliances (See the text for additional explanation).

São Paulo's participation in the alliance was accomplished through the person of Adhemar de Barros, formerly Vargas's caretaker in the state. In 1950, Barros felt strong enough to create his own political party, the PSP, and in 1955 and 1960, he was an independent candidate for the presidency, carrying Rio and São Paulo in 1955, but getting only about 25 percent of the national votes. It is clear that Barros was always a regional candidate, who did not fit the national cleavage between PSD-PTB and UDN.

The election of Jânio Quadros in 1960 was São Paulo's first and only victory. Quadros emerged without the support of any well organized party structure, and climbed step by step from the local government in the city of São Paulo to the presidency. His appeal was personal, his only issues were honesty and severity; his personal figure was unclean and unkempt, in contradiction with the broomstick which was his electoral symbol. To pass from local to national politics, he had to be absorbed by the UDN ticket, even though he had little in common with this party. He was able, when in the government, to attract the opposition of almost everyone, and resigned from office after eight months, leaving the country in a crisis from which it would not recover.(23)

Quadros' election did not mean that the balance between the co-optation vs. the representation systems inclined towards the latter, but rather that it had been superseded by a new cleavage between the tendencies towards the expansion and those towards the restriction of the political system. Balloting for vice president was done separately, and João Goulart, the Vice Presidential candidate from the PSD-PTB coalition, defeated his opponent, who was well-identified as a man from the UDN. The PSD-PTB presidential candidate was a general identified with leftist, nationalist groups, and the acceptance of his candidacy by the PSD was an indication of the party's inability to articulate a winning candidate of its own. General Lott was a loser on many accounts. His surprisingly high returns in the state of Minas Gerais is really an indication of the PSD's difficulty to act independently of official determinations emanating from the central government.

The erosion of the PSD-PTB hegemony can be better analyzed through Table 17, in which, data for congressional elections are displayed. The PSD never ceased to be the biggest party, but its relative size fell progressively as time passed. Alliance and coalitions of all kinds tended to absorb up to 50 per cent of the congressional votes. An analysis of these coalitions has not yet been made, but Table 17 and 18 presents both the data on coalitions and an attempt to classify them according to the dominant party in the three states of São Paulo, Minas Gerais and Guanabara. This attempt is, of course, provisional, and should be backed by a detailed analysis of the political processes in each state - which would be out of place here. It is enough to note here how the three parties in the co-optation system disappeared completely from São Paulo in 1962 as independent political entities.

TABLE 17
CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS, PARTY VOTES AND VOTES FOR COALITIONS (VALID VOTES): 1945-1962. PERCENTAGE FIGURES
  PSD PTB UDN PSP Others Alliances and coalitions
1945 44.00% 10.50% 27.40%   22.10% .
1950 27.00% 16.40% 17.00% 7.30% 12.10% 20.20%
1954 23.10% 15.60% 14.30% 9.30% 10.70% 27.00%
1958 19.00% 15.90% 14.30% 2.50% 11.50% 35.90%
1962 18.30% 14.20% 13.20% 1.00% 5.00% 48.30%
Source: Calculated from Brazil, Tribunal Superior Eleitoral, Dados Estatísticos, vol. 6, 1964.

The disappearance of the big national parties in São Paulo was followed, not by an increase in political regionalism but, paradoxically, by a progressive nationalization of state politics. If we look at the congressional alliances in this state, we notice that, in the 1958 election, the PSP entered into an alliance with the PSD, even though the former was clearly dominant (it had 411,510 votes for the state chamber, as opposed to the PSD's 181,700). In 1962, the PSD - PSP alliance came in second to an alliance of two regional parties (Christian Democrats and MTR), which also benefited from Jânio Quadros' political inheritance in the state. In Rio, the Labor Party entered into an alliance with the socialists, and received the support of the illegal but active Communist party. Only in Minas Gerais did the party configuration remain remarkably stable, with a coalition between the small PTB and the even smaller PSP in that state.

TABLE 18
CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS. PARTY VOTES: THREE STATES, 1945-1962: PERCENTAGES OF VALID VOTES
  PSD PTB UDN PSD Others Coalitions and alliances
Guanabara (city of Rio de Janeiro)
1945 17.50% 26.90% 23.10% 2.30% 30.20%  
1950 14.00% 39.80% 17.90% 7.20% 21.10% . .
1954 10.30% 29.50% (32.90)% 11.10% 16.20% 35.00%
1958 14.80% 28.70% 33.80% 20.60% 2.10% 14.80%
1962 13.90% 49.80% 30.00% . 6.30% 63.70%
Minas Gerais
1945 47.00% 7.20% 22.20% . . 23.60%  
1950 38.70% 12.90% 29.30% 3.10% 16.00%  
1954 44.90% 12.50% 25.10% 4.50% 13.00%  
1958 43.00% 12.30% 19.90% 3.60% 12.20%  
1962 42.60% (15.40)% 31.30%   10.70% 15.40%
São Paulo
1945 36.00% 17.90% 21.50% 5.50% 19.10%  
1950 15.30% 20.90% 13.10% 29.20% 21.50%  
1954 29.40% 17.20% 8.70% 24.50% 20.20%  
1958   10.70% 9.70% (38.50)% 41.10% 62.00%
1962   (15.10)%   (28.20)% 56.70% 89.30%
Source: Calculated from Brasil, Tribunal Superior Eleitoral, Dados Estatísticos, vol. 6, 1.964. Figures in parentheses correspond to votes given to alliances (See the text for additional explanation).

The 1962 congressional election was characterized, both in Rio and São Paulo, by the presence of strong candidates who concentrated the votes. Leonel Brizola, from the PTB-PSB alliance, concentrated 62.8 per cent of the votes of his coalition while Amaral Netto, from the UDN, got 47.5 per cent of his party's votes. Emílio Carlos, in São Paulo, got 44 per cent of the votes of his PTN-MTR alliance. In Minas Gerais, however, the most popular candidate, Sebastião Paes de Almeida of the PSD received only 80,000 votes (as opposed. to Brizola's 269,000, Amaral Netto's 123,000, and Emílio Carlos' 154,000), comprising only 10.6 per cent of his party's votes. The concentration of votes in legislative elections was a sign of the ideological polarizations which were taking place in the urban centers; however, it was characteristically absent in Minas Gerais.(24) During this period, congressional representation was proportional to the state's population, but enfranchisement was limited to the literate. This added strength to states like Minas Gerais, which practically were not affected by the increase in mobilization politics that characterized Rio, São Paulo and a few other big urban centers, like Recife and Porto Alegre. A gap started to develop between the politics leading to executive posts and the politics leading to congressional elections. The latter process remained stable and absorbed much of the mobilization effects; the former was much more exposed to these effects. The PSD-PTB coalition was palatable to the army and to conservative sectors, while the PSD was in the lead, but when Goulart had to replace Quadros, the crisis broke. The first solution, characteristically, was to force a parliamentary system which could empty the powers of the President. This was done in 1961, but Goulart was strong enough in 1963 to call a national plebiscite which restored his full constitutional powers. After this, the crisis was irreversible, and led to his overthrow in 1964.

7. Conclusions

If one wants to generalize from these changing voting patterns, the following traits seem to be most relevant.

Two lines of cleavage defined the political system in 1945. One was regionally marked, and corresponded to the co-optation vs. representation systems. The other existed within each of these systems, and went roughly from left (the PTB) to right (the UDN) on the co-optation side. In the São Paulo area, the left was represented in 1945 by the Communist Party (it got almost 20 per cent of the congressional vote in that state, but only 8.2 per cent of the national vote, and was finally declared illegal in 1947). The center right never acquired a definite party configuration in that state.

As time passed and the levels of education, urbanization, and industrialization increased, the co-optation system started to falter. Participation increased, and political alienation, as indicated by the proportion of null to valid votes, also increased;(25) this was particularly acute in the São Paulo area, in congressional elections. The pattern of political alienation for presidential elections is less clear(26).

TABLE 19
BRAZIL, TURNOUT FIGURES FOR 1945-1966: ELECTIONS FOR THE PRESIDENCY AND CHAMBERS OF DEPUTIES
Year Total population (1,000)a Percent of registered voters / population Percent of actual voters / population Actual / registered voters Per cent of blank and null votes / votes
Presidential elections Chamber of deputies
1945 46,590 16.2% 12.8% 83.1% 2.3% 3.2%
1950 51,944 22.0% 15.8% 72.1% 4.3% 7.0%
1954 59,564 25.3% 16.6% 6550.0%   6.6%
1955 61,469 24.8% 14.8% 59.7% 5.2%  
1958 67,184 20.5%b 18.9% 92.0%b   9.1%
1960 70,992 21.9% 19.0% 81.0% 7.2%  
1962 75,695 24.6% 19.6% 79.6%   17.7%
1966 85,139 26.3% 20.3% 77.2%   21.1%
1970 94,508 30.6% 23.7% 77.4%   30.3%
a Population figures are from the Brazilian census for 1950, 1960, and 1970, with interpolations for other years; b The decrease in registration and increase of the actual registered voters for this year is due to a renewal of the official enrollment lists. Source: Brasil, Tribunal Superior Eleitoral, Dados Estatísticos, 8 volumes, 1964-1971.

TABLE 20
INVALID (BLANK AND NULL) VOTES, PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS (PERCENTAGES)
year São Paulo Guanabara(city of Rio) Minas Gerais Brazil
1945 3.1% 1.3% 1.3% 2.3%
1950 4.2% 4.6% 4.6% 4.3%
1955 3.5% 2.5% 6.6% 5.2%
1960 5.1% 4.3% 10.0% 7.2%
Source: Brasil, Tribunal Superior Eleitoral, Dados Estatísticos, 8 volumes, 1964-1971.

TABLE 21
INVALID (BLANK AND NULL) VOTES, CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS (PERCENTAGES)
year São Paulo Guanabara (city of Rio) Minas Gerais Brazil
1945 3.9% 1.5% 1.9% 3.2%
1950 9.3% 5.4% 6.6% 7.0%
1954 7.6% 4.5% 6.5% 6.6%
1958 13.6% 6.9% 9.5% 9.2%
1962 29.8% 15.6% 15.1% 17.7%
1966 35.3% 25.3% 17.3% 21.1%
1970 34.6% 24.6% 39.7% 30.2%
Source: Superior Tribunal Eleitoral, 8 volumes, for 1945-1966; and Boletim Eleitoral, XXI, 241, August 1971, for 1970.

São Paulo's entrance as an independent political agent into national politics was first made in terms of representational politics of a stabilizing or restrictive character which acquired, however, almost immediately a mobilizational connotation. An analysis of interest groups, the trade unions, and even the educational system in the São Paulo area indicate the basis of its representational politics, but its alienation from national politics meant that these groups never assumed the shape of articulated political parties The PSP started, from the beginning, using mobilizational appeals, and used as much political co-optation as was possible at the state level.

The victory of Jânio Quadros (UDN- São Paulo) and Goulart (PTB) in the presidential elections of 1960 had two essential consequences. First, it meant that politics had become national, and that the political isolation of São Paulo had come to an end. Second, and perhaps more important, it meant that the route towards the nationalization of politics was via an increase in political mobilization and the emergence of clearly ideological cleavages at the national level. Minas Gerais, which had had the same political profile as the rest of the country in presidential and congressional elections up to 1954, lost its place to Guanabara, which had set the pattern for the 1960 presidential election.

Although the balance of forces was adequate for a political system based on limited suffrage, co-optation of political leaders, and electoral isolation of the economic centers, it could not be maintained when mobilization increased and politics became national. Political co-optation through mobilization of the urban centers demanded a kind of mobilization system, which lacked organizational support, as well as economic, military and international backing. The alternative was to restrict the levels of political participation and force the re-introduction of a restrictive type of co-optation. The new arrangement, after 1964, would increase the power of the executive, but channeling, at the same time, political participation through a two-party system in the legislature. It is worth noting that this formula was acceptable to the PSD, which could continue patronage politics at the local level, while counting on a strong executive to restrict attempts at political mobilization.
TABLE 22
CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS OF 1966 AND 1970 (PERCENTAGES OF VOTES)
  São Paulo Minas Gerais Guanabara Brazil
1966 1970 1966 1970 1966 1970 1966 1970
ARENA (government) 34.6% 48.6% 63.6% 48.5% 20.4% 25.3% 50.5% 48.4%
MDB (Opposition) 30.0% 16.7% 19.0% 12.2% 54.2% 50.0% 28.4% 21.2%
blank and null 35.4% 34.6% 17.4% 39.7% 25.4% 24.6% 21.1% 30.2%
Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%
Source: IBGE, Anuário Estatístico do Brasil, 1966; and Boletim Eleitoral, XXI, for 1970.

Regional politics apparently disappeared with the two-party system. However, the high levels of participation in São Paulo during the 1960 elections faded; the same thing happened in Guanabara. With the restriction of mobilization, political alienation increased, and the Congress entered a downhill race which ended in its complete subordination to the executive.(27) A new kind of co-optation system was installed, based on a military and technical mandate, and the political system came to a level of almost complete closure.

If the analysis is correct so far, some conclusions seem to follow necessarily. It becomes clear that political cleavages in an underdeveloped country like Brazil cannot be understood in terms of more or less explicit variable such as "modern" and "traditional," or rural - urban. Brazil shares with the rest of Latin America an outstanding lack of agrarian parties, and this is a strong indication that political cleavages do not cut along the rural - urban line. The party which came closest to being a rural party in Brazil was the PSD, but its strength lay, not in the countryside, but in the control and exploitation of a huge and complex governmental structure.

Another conclusion is that the Brazilian internal political process simply cannot be explained away by its insertion into an international context of dependency. External factors are obviously very important in the sense that they place limits on the alternatives, which are open to the country, but they are not sufficient to explain the developments that led to the present political configuration of the country.

We can now return to the opening question: what kind of political reopening is possible in Brazil? We can certainly say that co-optation politics with limited participation no longer seems possible in a non coercive regime. As the State rationalizes to cope with the pressures of underdevelopment in a context of demographic explosion and rising aspirations, piece-meal patronage becomes unsatisfactory and politically inefficient.(28) What was formerly a sound political career based on administrative advocacy becomes political corruption. Brazil is now witnessing the death of its old "political class."(29) Much of this process is in the hands of the government and manifested through direct and indirect sanctions. In addition to this, the process is hampered by its lack of function in a context polarized between administrative and economic efficiency and political mobilization.

The prospects for representation with limited participation are even dimmer. The 1932 Revolution in São Paulo was probably the peak of many attempts to establish an autonomous political force in the country vis-a-vis the co-optation system. After 1945, this kind of politics in São Paulo led more to political withdrawal than to party structure and organization; when São Paulo emerged again on the national political scene, it was in terms of charismatic mobilization and expanded participation. As the government extends its control over the economic system and increases its role a., an entrepreneur as well as its participation in all sectors of the country's life, it is indeed difficult to admit the possibility of an open political system, based on traditional representational politics in the foreseeable future.

The three remaining possibilities are that a political opening will not occur, or that it will occur with expanded participation in either the representation or co-optation mode. There is no reason to assume that the political system cannot remain closed or highly restricted for a long period, with some oscillations. Scattered empirical evidence seems to indicate that the urban middle sectors are willing to accept and support a closed, military backed regime, if the economic crisis is not overwhelming, and the demographic explosion does not lead to a crisis in the countryside. The social costs of this alternative are, of course, an entirely different matter.

Expanded participation in terms of representation is difficult to conceive, since it would require fundamental changes in the present governmental organization. The final possibility is mobilization with and through the governmental structure, with or without the present leadership. This alternative has been intensely discussed in terms of the Peruvian experience, and it is not beyond the range of possibilities.(30)

The future is, of course, unknown, and each of the possible alternatives must be ultimately tested by its efficiency in coping with the tensions of underdevelopment. One of the main difficulties, which will certainly arise in any attempt at political openness, will be the almost total lack of a new civilian leadership. The system of the 1945-64 period did not leave heirs, just orphans. The major political problem for Brazil in the years to come will be its ability to establish forms of autonomous and legitimate representation within a governmental structure, which seems to become progressively more centralized and overwhelming. This is not a problem which can be easily solved - and it is not merely a Brazilian problem either.



Notes

1. In a well publicized press interview on January 5, 1973, the President of the Brazilian Senate, Filinto Muller declared that liberal democracy was something of the past in the whole world, in an effort to legitimize the notion that the issue of political openness should be dropped as something irrelevant and old-fashioned. The repercussions of his speech, however, seem to indicate that the issue was more alive in the beginning of 1973 than he would probably like to admit. Cf. for instance Jornal do Brasil (1973).

2. See for instance Theodore Lowi (1969).

3. Samuel P. Huntington (1968), p 7.

4. Samuel P. Huntington (1968), p. 12.

5. The functionality of conflicts as a function of their level of intensity is something which was left out of Coser's classic study on Simmel. Cf. Lewis Coser (1956).

6. E. Schattschneider (1960).

7. "Real" here means only that they are not actually contested, that is, that these demands are not actually suppressed by physical coercion and/or ideological bombardment. See the following chapter, footnote 9.

8. There is a tradition in political sociology which stresses the functional aspects of corruptive practices in the workings of political systems, as long as these practices allow for the institutionalization of some "illegitimate" forms of political participation. This functionality is usually seen as dysfunctional from a technical standpoint, and A. O. Cintra notes that "in the debate between technical and political solutions, the responsibility for corruption is usually attributed to politics" (Personal communication). Our discussion shows that the responsibility can also be placed on the technical side. See, for the functionality of political corruption, the classic example of R. K. Merton (1957). I am indebted to Antonio Octávio Cintra for drawing my attention to this point.

9. Torcuato S. Di Tella links the complexity of Argentina's society and the plurality of its centers of power to the well- known difficulties which strong non-democratic dictatorships have of remaining in power. His generalization concerning Argentina, which includes Chile and Uruguay, is not too convincing in that he fails to consider what a long period of political confrontation can mean to a country in terms of political decay. What he considers to be "complexity" and "differentiation" could probably be better understood in terms of the relative strength of the representational pattern of political participation in those countries. With this change, it would probably be easier to include Brazil which, within the same line of reasoning, is certainly not less complex and differentiated than those countries. Cf. Torcuato S. Di Tella (1972).

10. The difficulty of considering these four levels independently is responsible for many mistakes in the literature on development. Celso Furtado, for instance, (1966), makes a sophisticated diagnosis of the economic crisis and its difficulties at the political level, but has little to say on the levels of social mobilization and political participation. He refers to the whole process of social development as a process of creation of "massas heterogêneas" (heterogeneous masses), and takes for granted the need for and feasibility of an "ideology of development" as the only way out. See my discussion of his book in Schwartzman (1967).

11. Cf. David E. Apter (1971), p. 29 and others, for a conceptualization of possible changes in systems of social stratification. Apter's book is the background of much of the discussion which follows, especially on the relationships between information, intelligence and coercion.

12. Analyses of leads and lags in the process of development, suggested by Karl F. Deutsch in his classic article on social mobilization, have been done independently by different authors with usually gratifying results. One of these currents is represented by Rosalind and Ivo K. Feierabend, who developed an index of "systemic frustration" by a comparison of indicators of '"want formation" (education, mass media, urbanization) with that of "want satisfaction" (economic growth). Another more structural line of research is followed by University of Zurich and Fundación Bariloche teams directed by Peter Heintz and Manuel Mora y Araujo. See Karl W. Deutsch (1966b); Rosalind and Ivo K. Feierabend (1966); Peter Heintz (1976); Simon Schwartzman (1972); Manuel Mora y Araujo (1972); Ruben Kaztman (1972); Alaor Passos (1968).

13. Rokkan and Lipset (1967).

14. For a historical description of the organization of the Brazilian political parties, cf. P. J. Peterson (1962).

15. The classic analysis of the coronelismo system in Brazilian politics is Victor Nunes Leal (1948). His main contention is that this system is not as much an expression of the strength of traditional leadership based on local, familistic and patrimonial ties, as it is of its weakness. The coronel, as a local boss in a stagnant economy, has little power, and no access to the government.

16. The best summary of the Brazilian labor system and its relations with the Ministry of Labor is given by Phillipe Schmitter (1971), chapter. v and viii.

17. The contrast between distributionist political "arenas", on one hand, and regulatory and redistributive arenas on the other, is developed for the United States by Theodore J. Lowi (1964). Although this study was based on a close scrutiny of decision making processes in the United States, there is little doubt that this framework could be very useful in a broader political spectrum. In Brazil's case, it seems clear that this framework could lead to a significant step further in the study of the repercussions of a system of political patrimonialism and co-optation at the decision making level.

18. For an analysis and up-dating on the study of Brazilian local politics, see José Murilo de Carvalho (1968); Bolivar Lamounier (1969); and especially Antônio Octávio Cintra (1971).

19. David Apter showed a clear perception of the limitations of the Western model of political representation, but I am a little uncertain about his ideas on the forms of participation which should correspond to his "hierarchical systems." See David Apter (1968).

20. It is easy to see that the cleavage in terms of representation vs. co-optation cuts across the class cleavage. Phillipe Schmitter shows very clearly that representation politics in Brazil was surprisingly inconspicuous even in period of open politics, manifesting itself mainly in the area of São Paulo. Many years earlier, Hélio Jaguaribe (1962). had already called attention to the cleavage between the "cartorial" and other autonomous sectors of the Brazilian social strata.

21. For an analysis of the development of the Brazilian Labor Party and its urban extraction, cf. Gláucio A. D. Soares (1972), in particular "As Bases Socioeconômicas dos Partidos Políticos." This forthcoming book is certainly the best source for a detailed understanding of the Brazilian political process in the 1945-64 period.

22. As usual, the details are very complex, although the pattern remains. See the details of the attempts and failures to create a national Central Union Organization in Brazil in Schmitter (1971), pp. 190-93. In a note, Schmitter quotes a "research" performed by the National Conference of Workers Circles, a Catholic organization, which shows that the newly created Confederação Nacional dos Trabalhadores was strongest in Pernambuco (71 per cent of the syndicates), Pará and Piaui (61 per cent), Maranhão (59 per cent), Guanabara (47 per cent) and Rio de Janeiro (47 per cent). If São Paulo is placed at the bottom, it becomes clear that the strength of this National Federation of Workers was almost perfectly and negatively correlated with industrialization.

23. For a keen analysis of Quadro' s resignation in terms of the developments in the Brazilian party system, cf. Hélio Jaguaribe (1961).

24. The concentration of legislative votes on a few candidates was not a new phenomenon of the early sixties but, in earlier years, it had usually been linked to strong, personalistic figures from the executive. Thus, Getúlio Vargas himself got 24.1 per cent of the votes of the city of Rio de Janeiro for the 1945 congressional election; in 1950, it was his son, Lutero Vargas, who concentrated 14.5 per cent of the state's votes (Vargas was then the presidential candidate). In 1954, Carlos Lacerda, a newspaperman who became notorious for his ferocious attacks on Vargas, got 24.2 per cent of the votes; he and Vargas' 5 son, Lutero, together obtained 42.5 per cent of the state's votes. In 1958, Lacerda had again 15.4 per cent of the state's votes; it is impossible to find the same pattern of concentration of votes in other states.

25. These figures on turnout must be considered in the light of the disenfranchisement of the illiterate (about 50 per cent of the population) and the population's age structure (about 50 per cent under 18). Since to register and vote was mandatory, abstention or lack of registration could create all sorts of difficulties in legal and bureaucratic procedures. It is expected, therefore, that turnout grows with increasing urbanization and education, and the rate of actual to registered voters is little more than a reflection of the up-dating of the electoral lists. The same is not true, however, for blank and null votes, which are a clear indication of political disaffection. The increase from 2.3 per cent to 21.1 per cent of these invalid votes is a first indication of the political system's progressive failure to correspond to the constituent's values and aspirations.

26. For an attempt to analyze the different state patterns of turnout and blank and null votes, cf. S. Schwartzman (1971).

27. Sérgio Henrique Hudson de Abranches and Gláucio A. D. Soares (1972); Wanderley Guilherme dos Santos (1972); and Clóvis Brigadão (1971).

28. The logic of this process was well characterized by Peter Heintz (1964).

29. The concept of "political class" belongs to Brazilian political jargon and expresses well the existence of a system of political leadership, which does not depend as much on the exercise of representation by other classes as it does on a special social position, defined by a relationship of dependency towards the State.

30. It is interesting to note that the "Peruvian way " used to attract the attention of Brazilians much more than the political process in Argentina, which seems, however, much closer to the restoration of representative democracy than do other military backed governments in Latin America. It is possible to speculate that the differences between Peru and Argentina might be traced back to the historical split, which freed Argentina from the Spanish colonial administration in Lima (I am indebted to Roberto Cortés-Conde for calling my attention to the parallel between São Paulo - Rio and Buenos Aires - Lima).